
Hypothetically speaking, let’s
assume this group of companies only contains two companies and that these two companies have arranged the minimum pricing agreement before, and in full knowledge of, a nearby long term oil contract
with the US. The oil contract being for an up and coming war, which due to
scarce resources and sudden great demand puts them in a weak bargaining
position (making them vulnerable to lose their consumer surplus).
Now, with this information, the dilemma really starts to be
of great importance. You and ‘company 2’ have agreed to share the contract profit
received equally (with each of you equally contributing to the oil supply as
well). The options and payoffs from this contact of one company, your company
are as follows:
(assuming that the contact is predicted to have a £25 mil profit
margin when demanded by you and company 2 with the agreed minimum price. Also you and company 2 being the
two only oil suppliers in the market).
Company 2: Your Decisions:
|
Cooperate
|
Compete
|
Cooperate
|
(£12.5mil), (£12.5mil)
|
(£0), (£20mil)
|
Compete
|
(£20mil), (£0)
|
(£5mil),(£5mil)
|
The top row represents your decisions which correlates to
the 2nd payoff in brackets. Company 2’s payoffs are listed first and are represented by the far left column.
Lets look at the options, option one, choosing to cooperate
has 2 possibilities. Firstly both of you follow this same line of logic and
both cooperate. This allows the greatest total profit to be obtained and shared
equally. The second outcome is that your opponent competes without your knowledge,
they then lower their profit margins to let’s say £20mil making themselves more
competitive and secure the contract. You therefore get nothing. When you choose
to compete, the same option applies to you when your opponent chooses to
cooperate, blindly ignorant of your deceitful ways. Lastly there is the option that both of you
compete, each trying to gain the advantage, then the price is determined by how
low each of you compete with each other to secure the contract. As you both are
competing against each other after agreeing £12.5mil profit margin each,
cooperating again is very unlikely so the likely price is to be less than
£12.5mil, let’s say £10mil profit for the overall contract. Due to ease of modelling,
let’s say that the US agrees a £5mil contract with both you and the other
company securing the same quantity of oil supplied. With these possible
outcomes comes the basis of prisoner’s dilemma and its application in
economics.
Now, imagine you are considering company two’s decisions. If
they cooperate then you can obtain £12.5mil by equally cooperating or £20mil by
competing. So you compete, it’s only logical! You gain £7.5mil greater profit.
So now imagine that company two decides to compete, if you cooperate you get
nothing but company 2 gets everything. If you compete too you at least get
£5mil, so you compete again. Competing is a dominant strategy for you and as
company 2 is in the same situation it is only logical that they will conclude
the same thing. Just ask what would the other player do, and what is the best
response to this. But wait, competing is the best strategy?
Let’s have a look
at this:
Company 2: Your Decisions:
|
Cooperate
|
Compete
|
Cooperate
|
(£12.5mil), (£12.5mil)
|
(£0), (£20mil)
|
Compete
|
(£20mil), (£0)
|
(£5mil),(£5mil)
|
The cells/ areas with a blue border represent Company 2’s
dominant strategy (to compete). The green filled cells/ areas represent your
dominant strategy (again to compete). Therefore the bottom right side cell is
the logical outcome, neither you nor company two can change your/their choice
and set to gain an advantage (assuming that the other stays with the original
choice to compete). There is no unilateral incentive for either of you to change from the original strategy. This is what is known as a Nash equilibrium. So, Nash’s equilibrium
tells us that the ideal solution, or rather rational solution is for both of
you to compete and gain £5mil each but wait, is this really the case? If both
cooperate you both gain £7.5mil greater than if you both compete, so is this
the rational solution at all? This is a major flaw in Nash’s equilibrium and is
an argument against game theory. Other arguments include that people aren't rational (emphasized in the Flood-Dresher experiment). On moves 83 through to
98 both player cooperated in the Flood Dresher experiment which was a simple
game to demonstrate the prisoner’s dilemma. Both players therefore reaped the
greatest benefits however this took at total of 82 turns before they began to sustainably cooperate. In our situation we have only one turn and a contract
of this significance is unlikely to come along anytime soon, so we can’t learn
our ‘opponent’s’, ‘company 2’s’ strategy. The late 1950’s Ohio state studies at
Ohio State University which followed a similar game to demonstrate the prisoner’s
dilemma showed that most participants chose to ‘compete’ or ‘defect’ most of
the time, following the dominant strategy and yet if they cooperated a greater
benefit could be achieved between them. The sum of cooperation pay outs is
greater than the sum of any other scenario in the table however it seems
fundamentally human nature to defect in aspiration of obtaining a greater
amount of wealth than your opponent. Perhaps its evolutionary or instinctive to
compete rather than cooperate, it’s human nature, or perhaps there is another explanation.
As one of the great unsolved dilemmas of game theory, the prisoner’s dilemma still poses a great flaw in it's very fundamental fabric of application and equally creates great questions about the very nature of human
beings and whether we are truly rational creatures. So, ask yourself, what
would you do?
This was a very interesting and thought provoking piece. My own personal take is that unfortunately it is human nature to compete. With only cooperation being a secondary instinct, when competing is non productive.
ReplyDelete